David Brooks on the U.S. Supreme Court and Affirmative Action - Speed of Ascent
David Brooks writes in The New York Times:
The Supreme Court didn’t exactly shock the world on Monday. But, by imposing
stricter standards on how courts review affirmative action plans, the court did
send another small signal that the era of explicitly race-based affirmative
action is coming to an end.
During their heyday, affirmative action programs
produced some lasting good. It would have been immoral in the civil rights era
to have an archipelago of white colleges and universities dotting the land.
Affirmative action plans prevented that. As William Bowen and Derek Bok wrote in
their classic work, “The Shape of the River,” in 1960, only 5.4 percent of
blacks between 25 and 29 had graduated from college, while, by 1995, that share
had risen to 15.4 percent. The share of black medical school students climbed
from 2.2 percent to 8.1 percent.
But affirmative action programs also perpetrated some
noteworthy wrongs. They reinforced crude racial categorizations, which repelled
many Americans. They discriminated against Asian-Americans. Thomas Espenshade of
Princeton reviewed admissions data from 1997 and found that Asian applicants had
to outscore African-Americans by 450 points on their S.A.T.’s to have an equal
chance of getting into a college. The programs also produced a mismatch between
minority students and the schools they attended, which sometimes ended up
hurting the students they were designed to help.
The evidence on this is hotly disputed, but Richard
Sander and Stuart Taylor Jr. make a compelling case in their book “Mismatch.”
Because some minority applicants get drafted into schools where they wouldn’t
otherwise be accepted, they are more likely to be stuck in the bottom of their
classes and more likely to flee from difficult science and engineering majors.
Black law school students are four times more likely to fail bar exams, with
mismatch, according to Sander and Taylor, explaining half this gap.
So affirmative action gave us some wildly good and
unfortunately negative outcomes, and it stirred up fierce debates. But that’s
not why these racial preferences are going away. They are going away because
underlying realities have changed.
First, economic inequality now trumps racial
inequality as the chief source of disadvantage. Sean Reardon of Stanford has
looked at a range of studies over 50 years and found whereas the black/white
test score gap used to be nearly twice as large as the rich/poor gap, now the
income gap is nearly twice large as the race gap. Given this, explicitly
race-based affirmative action just doesn’t respond to the needs of the moment.
Second, the ethnic makeup of the country has become
more complex. At the dawn of the affirmative action era, it was easy to see the
chief racial divide as between whites and blacks, but the ethnic mosaic is much
more complicated now, with an explosion of different groups from all over the
world, at various levels of disadvantage.
Third, we’re living in an age of data. Once, it may
have seemed reasonable to measure a person by a few crude metrics: S.A.T.,
G.P.A., race. But now colleges and universities, especially with financial aid
forms, have access to a wide array of data on all applicants and can potentially
get a much more personalized look at the disadvantages each individual has
overcome.
The result is that race-based affirmative action,
while not being rejected, is being subsumed within class-based affirmative
action. It’s being subsumed within more detailed measures of exactly which
challenges each applicant faced.
In his Century Foundation report, “A Better
Affirmative Action,” Richard Kahlenberg shows how state university systems in
places like Texas and Colorado and at places like the U.C.L.A. Law School are
devising class-based preference systems, which ameliorate economic disadvantage
while still producing racially diverse campuses.
What often happens is this: Voters or courts in a
state will strike down race-based affirmative action. Minority enrollments
initially plummet. Then administrations devise class-based systems that look at
the specific obstacles that applicants have overcome: growing up in a
neighborhood with concentrated poverty, with a single parent or in a home with
few financial assets. Minority enrollments recover, at least to a significant
degree, and the new system is fairer than the old.
What are we looking for when we admit a student into a
university? We’re looking for speed of ascent, not academic attainment at one
moment in time. A student who’s risen from an economic catastrophe to achieve a
B-plus average has more speed of ascent than the child of law professors who has
an A average. The first student may be more expensive to teach. She may not
write as many big alumni checks. But she’ll reflect more credit on her school
and society.
We now have the means to measure speed of ascent in a
fairer and better way. Explicit, raced-based affirmative action programs weren’t
wrong for their time, but they are being replaced.
0 Comments:
Post a Comment
<< Home